![]() |
The general principle that land value is a good source of public revenue is surprisingly uncontroversial among economists. Many recognize that the rent of land is not a payment for any sort of production; land is not produced. Land rent (and/or rent capitalized into a selling price) simply induces one person to give over exclusive access to a piece of land to another. It does not affect the supply of land. This means that land rent is an economic surplus, which can be heavily taxed, or even fully taken by the community, without putting any burden on production.
The main source of these extremely low figures for aggregate rent is, in the United States, the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA). This is the basic source for the tallying-up of the Gross Domestic Product, and its raw data comes from that given to the Internal Revenue Service from income tax filers. The rent figure in the NIPA accounts is called "Rental Income of Persons" and includes rent explicitly paid for rented real estate, as well as the "imputed rent" that homeowners pay to themselves. It does not, however, include rent that is paid in local property taxes, is capitalized into selling prices of land (this income is recorded as "capital gains") or is counted in the value of corporate assets. Clearly this 1-2% figure is inadequate as a measure of aggregate rent. These low aggregate rent figures are corroborated by figures published by the Federal Reserve Board and the National Bureau of Economic Research. (1) As often happens in economic-policy discussions, the real source of this discrepancy is a conflict of definitions. Advocates of collecting land rent for public revenue are accustomed to thinking of "rent" as the return to land as a distinct factor of production, as we have defined it in this course. However, mainstream economists — and particularly those who compile national income data — tend not to use this definition. Mainstream, or "Neoclassical" economics has consistently denied the existence of land as a separate factor of production. Data from Australia![]() The "Henry George Theorem"At first glance, the Henry George Theorem would seem to suggest that while land rent would most likely be sufficient for local or municipal revenue, it would not be enough to cover the revenue needs of higher levels of government, such as the cost of Interstate highways, national defense, or welfare-state protections. However, it should be pointed out that the Henry George Theorem applies only to location values within cities, under existing economic conditions (conditions which include the state and federal tax burdens in those cities). Also, there are many other forms of natural opportunity, whose rents could be part of the overall tax base. The most comprehensive study of the sufficiency of rent as a revenue base is "The Hidden Taxable Capacity of Land: Enough and to Spare," by Mason Gaffney. (4) This long article surveys the many ways in which land is glossed over, hidden, misnamed, underreported, neglected, disregarded and just plain ignored in many areas of conventional economic analysis. Gaffney starts from the unconventional, but highly sensible, position that land is a distinct factor of production. Noting the general agreement among economists about land's suitability as a revenue source, Gaffney sets out to discover what he can about its extent. He finds that land per se — bounded parcels of the earth's surface — is worth far more than conventional sources say it is, particularly in urban areas. However, Gaffney's tactic of looking for the role of land wherever it might be found (despite efforts to obscure it) bring to light many other sources of socially-beneficial revenue that can come from natural opportunities.
How Taxation Affects Land RentThis principle is easiest to see if we look at shifting taxes off of buildings and onto land. Taxes levied against a building are part of the annual cost of that building. That is money that cannot be part of the finance cost of the building; this means, in effect, that the builder can't afford to build as big a building as she could were there no tax. Smaller buildings means less rentable space, less income, and therefore lower demand for land. If the tax is shifted from the building to the land, a given value/quality of building is now less expensive than before. This means demand for land increases. Another way of saying this is that if taxes on buildings are decreased, the tax base is not lost; it is shifted to land value, where it can be efficiently and economically collected. (And, as we have already discussed, shifting the tax to land values would increase the cost of holding land for speculation. This would stimulate more construction, further increasing economic activity and demand for land in that area.)
There are many good theoretical reasons why land rent — properly assessed and collected by the community — would comfortably cover all our public revenue needs. Many Georgists hold that there would be more than enough, and that a per-capita dividend could also be provided. (7) Nevertheless, the question of "How much rent is there?" cannot be quantitatively answered. The data needed to determine aggregate national rent simply has not been collected (Dwyer's data from Australia is the best we have). The Henry George Theorem at least supplies a firm theoretical model suggesting that land rents are sufficient for local revenue needs. However, it is important to realize that our current system of taxation depresses land rents. Were taxes on labor and capital to be replaced by public collection of rent, the level of aggregate rent (our prospective tax base) would be far higher than it is now. And, it's worth pointing out that in a highly productive, full-employment economy, such as we can envision with Henry George's remedy in effect, government would need less revenue than now. There would be far less demand for government to mop up a dysfunctional economy's messes. NOTES
|